Laserfiche WebLink
<br />G,),) , ;:i <br /> <br />puts such "off-land" users as municipalities in a <br />better position than they would occupy under the <br />American Rule. Early appropriators for off-land <br />users are favored over later appropriators, Over- <br />lying landowners. however, are treated some- <br />what equally in that they can be ratably restricted <br />in times of shortage. Large volume users, how- <br />ever, are favored over low-volume users since <br />user rights are correlated on the basis of current <br />and beneficial needs. Early users are favored <br />somewhat over later users or deferred users <br />since the California Ruledoes not permitwaterto <br />be saved tor future use. <br /> <br />Physical-Hydrologic and Environmental <br />Impacts <br /> <br />The operation of the California Rule is much <br />too complex. 10 facilitate an accurate description <br />of physical-hydrologic and environmental <br />impacts. The most that can be said is that the rule <br />offers a potential to prevent total exhaustion of <br />an aquifer because of provisions that mandate <br />sharing and pro rata reductions in time of <br />shortage. <br /> <br />Alternative #5: Adopt a Rule of <br />Reasonable Use as developed in <br />certain eastern states as the <br />definition of groundwater <br />property rights in Nebraska. <br /> <br />Description and Methods of <br />Implementation <br /> <br />Certain eastern states have resolved ground- <br />water disputes on the basis of riparian principles. <br />namely on a substantive determination of what <br />use is reasonable in a given circumstance.3D <br />Where riparian principles are applied, the rights <br />of individual landowners overlying an aquifer are <br />correlated. Landowners have a right to use <br />groundwater but only to the extent that others <br />are not injured thereby. The American Rule. in <br />contraSl,sanctlons uses which injure other over- <br />lying landowners by depleting the aquifer as long <br />as the depleting landowner is not transporting <br />the water off the overlying land. <br />An extreme interpretation of this rule would <br />limit extractions to no more than the sustainable <br />yield of the aquifer. A more relaxed version 01 the <br />rule would permit aquifer dewatering. but only as <br />long as court-defined superior uses were not <br />interfered with. Such ad hoc determinations <br />create great uncertainty of right, so much un- <br />certainty in fact. that the rule probably cannot <br />function as a rule of property but only as a rule of <br />tort. A more complete development of the tort law <br /> <br />approach to groundwater property rights is <br />discussed in Alternative #6. <br /> <br />Socio-Economic Impacts <br /> <br />While a reasonable use rule would be extreme- <br />ly flexible, it would offer landowners almost no <br />security of right. The investment deterrent of <br />potential future ad hoc determinations of use <br />rights would act as a significant barrier to attain. <br />ing economic efficiency in water use. In some <br />respects. this rule is even less secure than the <br />Engish Rule since a landowner cannot rely on an <br />ability to out-capture his neighbor. On the other <br />hand, the flexibility of the rule would permit <br />judges to reallocate water in a more efficient <br />manner if the circumstances demanded realloca- <br />tion_ Judges would not necessarily strive for <br />economic efficiency. however, nor would they <br />necessarily be capable of evaluating economic <br />effiCiency in use even if that were perceived as a <br />goal. <br />The ad hoc nature 01 use determinations under <br />this rule makes it impossible to evaluate equity <br />impacts. All that can be said is that no particular <br />groups are inherently favored over other parti- <br />cular groups of users. <br />Physical-Hyrologic and Environmental <br />Impacts <br />Since property rights would be subject to ad <br />hoc judicial interpretation under this alternative, <br />no basis exists to predict physical-hydrologic or <br />environmental impacts. While judicial power <br />could be used to minimize adverse impacts, the <br />rule offers no assurance that judicial power <br />would, in fact. be used to minimize adverse <br />impacts. <br /> <br />Alternative #6: Adopt the reason. <br />able use rules found in the <br />RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF <br />TORTS 9 858 as the definition of <br />groundwater property rights in <br />Nebraska. <br /> <br />Description and Methods of <br />Implementation <br /> <br />RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS 9 858 <br />(1979) provides as follows: <br />Liability for Use of Groundwater <br />(1) A proprietor of land or his grantee who <br />withdraws groundwater from the land and <br />uses it for a beneficial purpose is not subject to <br />liability for interference with the use of water <br />by another, unless <br />(a) the withdrawal of groundwater unreason- <br /> <br />3-9 <br />