My WebLink
|
Help
|
About
|
Sign Out
Home
Browse
Search
Wetland Resource Group Meeting March 9 1993
CWCB
>
Water Supply Protection
>
DayForward
>
7001-8000
>
Wetland Resource Group Meeting March 9 1993
Metadata
Thumbnails
Annotations
Entry Properties
Last modified
2/16/2016 10:28:50 AM
Creation date
2/14/2014 11:19:27 AM
Metadata
Fields
Template:
Water Supply Protection
Description
Meeting materials for the Wetland Rescource Group Meeting held March 9, 1993.
State
CO
Basin
Statewide
Date
3/9/1993
Author
Colorado DNR
Title
Resource Group Meeting March 9 1993
Water Supply Pro - Doc Type
Meeting
There are no annotations on this page.
Document management portal powered by Laserfiche WebLink 9 © 1998-2015
Laserfiche.
All rights reserved.
/
14
PDF
Print
Pages to print
Enter page numbers and/or page ranges separated by commas. For example, 1,3,5-12.
After downloading, print the document using a PDF reader (e.g. Adobe Reader).
Show annotations
View images
View plain text
level through wetlands creation and, more realistically, wet- <br />lands restoration. <br />So how do we get there? Imagine an application to fill a <br />wetlands area where the fore_one development values of <br />pen-nit denial are exceptionally high and the environmental <br />benefits of avoidance are questionable. Undercurrent inflex- <br />ible sequencing rules, neither the foregone development <br />value or environmental outcomes of permit denial would be <br />considered. And if for some reason the permit is granted, <br />compensation would focus primarily on in -kind and on -site <br />replacement. The economy and the environment stand to <br />lose. We need to„iurn wetlands regulation to a broader goal, <br />by creating markets for wetlands functions and by overcom- <br />ing the inflexibility that creates high economic and environ- <br />mental costs. <br />How do we do that? By recognizing that a market -based <br />policy is the next generation of reform beyond mitigation <br />banking. The mitigation bank is a tool to make off -site <br />compensation for wetlands losses which are permitted in the <br />regulatory program. But there are limitations to the current <br />ideas about banking. First, compensation ratios when a <br />permit is granted seek no net loss of functions. Restoration <br />should achieve a net gain where more than one unit of credit <br />is expected in return for each unit of permitted loss. Also, <br />the mitigation bank relies on the wetlands developer to <br />undertake restoration or creation as the deposit to the bank. <br />For most permit applicants, this is financially unworkable. <br />For the watershed, the wetlands compensations required are <br />too small to realize the scale economies that might be <br />achieved by larger scale restoration. And placing the respon- <br />sibility for successful restoration and creation on people who <br />have neither the expertise, experience, or long-term interest <br />in wetlands and watersheds dooms many restorations to <br />failure. <br />A market -based policy begins with a recognition: the <br />applicant wants a permit. but the regulatory agency wants to <br />protect and restore the ecological functions of watersheds. <br />These incompatible objectives have the potential for deal <br />making, which is the essence of markets. A market -based <br />permitting program will separate the decision on the grant- <br />ing of a permit from decisions about where and when to <br />restore wetlands. <br />A market -based approach includes a permit review proc- <br />ess whereby the magnitude of development value is consid- <br />ered in granting a permit. A share of that development value <br />is then captured by the agency and put toward the benefit of <br />the watershed. The system works through the exchange of <br />money and permits in order to support scientifically sound <br />and well - managed wetlands restoration programs, toward <br />the goal of net -gain. The recipient of a wetlands develop- <br />ment pen-nit makes the money payment either to the permit- <br />ting agency or to a private firm which restores wetlands and <br />sells the credits directly to wetlands developers. <br />I expect to hear opposition to market -based approaches, <br />so let me anticipate two of the arguments. Some in the <br />development community might be opposed to a share -the- <br />gain rule for setting compensation ratios and fees. Yet for the <br />society at large to be willing to move beyond the current- <br />sequencing rules there must be some perceived opportunity <br />to be environmentally better off with- versus - without any <br />given permit being issued. When a permit is granted with a <br />no- net -loss regulatory goal, all of the net economic returns <br />accrue to the applicant. A share - the -gain approach could <br />secure some of that return for wetlands programs. There <br />6 NATIONAL WETLANDS NEWSLETTER <br />must be a willingness to share gains — not claim extortion <br />or a taking. As noted earlier, the current regulatory program <br />already implicitly imposes a development tax. This proposal <br />simply makes the tax explicit. <br />The wetlands protection establishment also will stand in <br />the way. Its concern is that degraded wetlands can never be <br />restored to their previous condition. Skepticism about wet- - <br />lands creation is even more widespread. This concern is <br />based on past experiences with restoration and creation <br />which have often not been successful. Unfortunately, critics <br />of restoration and creation fail to distinguish between fail- <br />ures of the science and failures from poor application of the <br />science. Most failures are probably attributable to unclear <br />goals. inadequate expertise in doing the restoration, and an <br />absence of monitoring to make modifications to the projects <br />over time. These are institutional failures which must be <br />addressed with policy and program reform, but should not <br />be used as an excuse to reject the possibility of successful <br />restoration and creation. <br />All of the preceding comments lead me to the subject of <br />classification, because the market -based approach depends <br />on classification. Wetlands management to serve the larger <br />purpose of watershed restoration would begin by initiating <br />a planning process of watershed re- design to establish the <br />sizes, types, and locations of wetlands /uplands complexes <br />that will have the potential for long -term survival as func- <br />tioning ecosystems. This could be accomplished in the <br />SAMP (Special Area Management Plan) process under the <br />Coastal Zone Management Act; in the Advanced Identifica- <br />tion Program under §404, or as part of a separate watershed <br />planning authority under state or regional authority. <br />Existing wetlands might be classified into three types <br />based on the following criteria. Criterion one would consider <br />the magnitude of the ecological value to the watershed of the <br />site proposed for development if the permit is denied. This <br />is a critical notion because the criterion acknowledges the <br />possibility of degradation, isolation; and fragmentation even <br />if the wetlands site is saved. The second criterion is the <br />difficulty and cost of restoring or creating lost functions if <br />the permit is granted. The third criterion is the magnitude of <br />the development value to the landowner that will be realized <br />if the permit is granted. The more the development value, <br />the more gain there is to share. <br />With these criteria three classes of wetlands follow: Class <br />I would be those wetlands of exceptionally high ecological <br />value, with functions that are costly or difficult to replicate <br />and for which development values are likely to be -low. <br />Avoidance is the best management strategy for these wet- <br />lands areas and only the most obvious water - dependent and <br />high -value development would be even considered for a <br />permit. <br />Class II wetlands are where the wetlands site now has <br />modest functional value to the watershed, or where the <br />current value will be compromised even if the permit for <br />filling is denied. These should also be wetlands where cost - <br />effective restoration of functions is possible and where de- <br />velopment values may be high enough to achieve the net - <br />gain goal. Some flexibility in sequencing is expected as <br />particular circumstances dictate. Class III wetlands would <br />be areas where a fixed development fee might be established <br />with only limited permit review being required. <br />General rules for classification can be established and <br />maps that describe protected areas and the lower value — <br />fee for development — areas might be depicted. However, <br />
The URL can be used to link to this page
Your browser does not support the video tag.