E
<br />0
<br />programs such as §404 and state programs that regulate land
<br />development by filling for urban uses— commercial, indus-
<br />trial, and residential purposes and public infrastructure—
<br />where that land continues to have wetlands characteristics
<br />according to some delineation procedures.
<br />Generally, those who seek a permit for wetlands filling
<br />must demonstrate to the satisfaction of the regulatory
<br />authorities that they have considered all "practicable" alter-
<br />natives to avoid the wetlands and that the activity proposed
<br />for the filled wetlands is water dependent.' And, when a
<br />permit is granted compensation for the filled wetlands in-
<br />kind and on -site, if at all possible, is expected. Taken to-
<br />gether, these are termed the "sequencing" rules.
<br />Over time the geographic scope of wetlands regulation
<br />and sequencing has expanded from riparian areas to isolated
<br />wetlands and to— possibly —areas where water may seldom
<br />reach the surface of the soil. The expanding geographic
<br />scope catches more land in the regulatory net and highlights
<br />three related concerns about wetlands regulation: inflexibil-
<br />ity, economic burden, and environmental loss.
<br />What is meant by inflexibility? In the sequencing review
<br />there is little concern for the costs of the foregone develop-
<br />ment opportunity to the applicant, the region, or the nation.
<br />And, no matter how degraded the wetlands, or no matter how
<br />isolated they are from a larger watershed, the current regu-
<br />latory program insists on avoidance for all activities not
<br />deemed to be water dependent.
<br />Inflexibility leads to economic burden and, perhaps, the
<br />undermining of the public consensus that has developed in
<br />support of wetlands management. To be blunt, the sequenc-
<br />ing and compensation requirements of current wetlands
<br />permitting are implicit taxes on land development, since all
<br />wetlands development bears a compensation cost for the
<br />functions lost. Of course, it pays a far greater cost if the
<br />permit is denied, since some share of the development value
<br />is lost.
<br />This implicit "tax" and the reduction of development
<br />value are most politically acceptable when the public inter-
<br />est gains from wetlands protection are the most clear. Hence
<br />the regulatory program was able to maintain support when
<br />riparian areas and certain isolated wetlands with obvious
<br />wetlands functions were the target of regulation. But as the
<br />geographic scope of the program expands, whatever the
<br />scientific merit of delineating areas as wetlands, the land
<br />subject to this implicit tax and development value reduction
<br />increases and the social consensus for the current permit
<br />program weakens. What was perceived initially as protec-
<br />tion of critical, but limited, areas of the environment appears
<br />to have become a national land settlement regulation and
<br />taxation policy through the back door of wetlands regula-
<br />tion.
<br />The inflexibility of sequencing can also work to the detri-
<br />ment of environmental improvement. There is- little attention
<br />paid to the fragmentation, isolation, and functional degrada-
<br />tion of the wetlands preserved or compensated for by in -kind
<br />and on -site creation and restoration. Commercial and resi-
<br />dential development winding among so- called protected
<br />wetlands is the product of the re gulatory rules which stress
<br />wetlands avoidance. Wetlands in the midst of concrete park-
<br />ing lots are the product of on -site compensation require-
<br />ments.
<br />The effect of this development — whether or not the prod-
<br />uct of the permit process —has often been to diminish the
<br />ecological functions of wetlands by polluted runoff, by
<br />changes in hydrologic regimes, and by the fragmentation of
<br />the landscape which isolates the wetlands from the surround-
<br />ing uplands, waters, and biological resources of the water-
<br />shed. These functional effects which occur away from the
<br />wetlands site, are uninventoried and escape regulation. As a
<br />result, in many areas wetlands exist, but their functions in
<br />the watershed are so degraded that their contribution to
<br />watershed processes is insignificant.
<br />To move beyond the current regulatory program and its
<br />problems, the nation needs a wetlands management pro-
<br />gram, as distinct from a wetlands regulatory program. Wet -
<br />lands management must be part of a total landscape perspec -.
<br />tive which recognizes two realities. First, wetlands protec-
<br />tion must be part of a total land settlement policy which
<br />resets market signals. And, also, wetlands per se are not the
<br />concern. Concern is.for the role wetlands play in support of
<br />watershed ecosystems.
<br />I will comment on land settlement only in passing, al-
<br />though it may be the more significant of the two points. In
<br />the not - too - distant past, markets did not allocate wetlands as
<br />we desired — they weren't being drained rapidly enough.
<br />We set about to make policy that encouraged drainage. These
<br />polices were a resounding success, since this rigged market
<br />induced landowners to _drain over 50 percent of the nation's
<br />wetlands, mostly for agriculture. Today, we have a new
<br />understanding of what we think of wetlands and these mar-
<br />ket outcomes are deemed to be undesirable.
<br />Deregulation of markets in the broadest sense may save
<br />wetlands more effectively than more regulation. To illus-
<br />trate, the 1985 "Swampbuster" reforms and the 1986 Tax
<br />Reform Act eliminated the incentives to conversion in the
<br />tax code. The results — in my view — have been to slow
<br />and indeed stop wetlands loss to agricultural conversion.
<br />Where do we go with this story now? Throughout the
<br />nation, the urban development pressure on nontidal and
<br />coastal wetlands is determined by the way people seek to
<br />settle the land. This land settlement has been described as
<br />sprawl. It seems to me — and I could elaborate — that
<br />government policy, more than the so- called free market, is
<br />at work in sprawling settlement over the landscape with one
<br />consequence being development pressure on wetlands.
<br />What policies am I talking about? Exclusionary zoning such
<br />as large lot subdivision rules, local government fiscal policy,
<br />failures to maintain the habitability of central cities and
<br />close -in suburbs, gasoline pricing policy, tax policy toward
<br />real estate, and many more. Reform these polices to let
<br />market forces work and sprawl will be diminished, much as
<br />reform of agricultural and tax policy to let the markets work
<br />has taken pressure off wetlands from agricultural develop-
<br />ment. Having said this let me return to the more mundane —
<br />reform of current wetlands regulation.
<br />The second message from landscape thinking is that the
<br />functional value of an existing wetland, in a given location,
<br />is established by its contribution to a larger aquatic system.
<br />We have to recognize that existing wetlands are an accident
<br />of the development process and do not necessarily bear any
<br />relationship to the optimal configuration of those wetlands
<br />within the landscape. We should be thinking about reinte-
<br />grating wetlands that have been lost or degraded into
<br />ecologically optimal locations. Wetlands regulation should
<br />acknowledge this watershed perspective. Instead, there re-
<br />mains a too strong tendency in the current regulatory pro-
<br />gram to protect the status quo and not look for opportunities
<br />to advance environmental improvement at the watershed
<br />JANUARY /FEBRUARY 1993 5
<br />
|