My WebLink
|
Help
|
About
|
Sign Out
Home
Browse
Search
7887
CWCB
>
UCREFRP
>
Public
>
7887
Metadata
Thumbnails
Annotations
Entry Properties
Last modified
7/14/2009 5:02:31 PM
Creation date
5/22/2009 6:55:04 PM
Metadata
Fields
Template:
UCREFRP
UCREFRP Catalog Number
7887
Author
Fischer, H., (Wendy E. Hudson, ed.).
Title
Building Economic Incentives Into The Endangered Species Act, Third Edition.
USFW Year
1994.
USFW - Doc Type
Washington, D.C.
Copyright Material
NO
There are no annotations on this page.
Document management portal powered by Laserfiche WebLink 9 © 1998-2015
Laserfiche.
All rights reserved.
/
128
PDF
Print
Pages to print
Enter page numbers and/or page ranges separated by commas. For example, 1,3,5-12.
After downloading, print the document using a PDF reader (e.g. Adobe Reader).
Show annotations
View images
View plain text
certain habitat and she wants to convert more than her 15 percent allocation, she <br />would have to buy the requisite development rights from other landowners. Such <br />development rights could be held and purchased by any interested party. Land- <br />owners creating new habitat would be eligible to market or exercise their develop- <br />ment rights on a 1:3 or 1:2 ratio (i.e., one unit of development rights per two or <br />three units of created habitat). <br />Rationale: Markets tend to work efficiently in determining resource allocations <br />because the best use of a scarce resource is matched with the greatest need, as <br />reflected in the price a party is willing to pay for the use of that resource. The <br />right to destroy or degrade important habitat is extraordinarily valuable. Creating <br />a market for these rights would allow their full economic value to be realized, and <br />could help ensure that a scarce and valuable resource would be used in society's <br />best interests. A market in habitat development rights could be plausible and <br />effective because such rights are a scarce and extremely valuable resource, and <br />the right, or amount of habitat to be traded, would be sharply defined by the FWS <br />during the initial allocation. <br />Precedent for this type of government action is widespread. The federal govern- <br />mentregularly defines quota levels during the HCP planning process -from the <br />amount of habitat that can be developed to the amount of clean air that can be <br />used up or dirtied, to the amount of various crops and commodities eligible for <br />price supports, to the amount of ocean-going fish that can be harvested. Trade- <br />able development and use rights are being used by the Environmental Protection <br />Agency in dirty air basins, by the Bureau of Reclamation for rights to federal <br />water, and by county governments to control housing density levels. <br />Benefits from a market in habitat development rights would be shared among <br />private landowners, overall biodiversity, and society in general: <br />• Private landowners would benefit from such a program because a <br />portion of their lands containing important habitat would be imbued with <br />financial value, rather than being a nuisance and a constraint. <br />• Development patterns would improve because the scarcity of develop- <br />ment rights would cause land to be used more efficiently. Nominally <br />profitable ventures causing habitat destruction would be rendered unprofit- <br />able. <br />• Perhaps most importantly, overall biodiversity would benefit because <br />the amount of habitat authorized to be destroyed would be clearly defined <br />and capped. The continual incremental losses of habitat currently sanc- <br />tioned by the FW S through less than obvious criteria would be halted. <br />Endangered species would also benefit because a powerful incentive to <br />create new habitat would be introduced. <br />14 <br />
The URL can be used to link to this page
Your browser does not support the video tag.