Laserfiche WebLink
implies. To work, a market requires both a clearly defined good or service, and a <br />sufficient quantity of this good or surplus to interest some critical mass of traders. <br />The FWS' delineation of critical habitat satisfies the first market requirement, but <br />by definition, endangered, and perhaps threatened status, implies that no further <br />loss of habitat is acceptable if the species' chances for survival and recovery are to <br />be maximized. Because a large number of species have been listed at population <br />levels far too small to assure long-term viability, the opportunity has probably <br />been missed to use habitat development rights as a tool for endangered species <br />conservation. However, should the ESA take on a more aggressive and proactive <br />effort to conserve biodiversity overall, as through ecosystem management, free- <br />market approaches may prove effective in preventing future endangerment. <br />The following proposal sketches the framework for a program of tradeable devel- <br />opmentrights. The long-range goal would be to establish a tradeable permit <br />program that targets habitats for candidate species and overall biodiversity. A <br />proper application of marketable development rights for these habitats could <br />ensure that they are used wisely and efficiently, with the result being that candi- <br />date species do not become endangered species, and that an effective tool is <br />created that will help us keep ahead of the endangerment curve. <br />Proo~al 7 - Creation of a Market for Development Rights on Important <br />Biological Habitat <br />Description: As with mineral rights, water rights, easements, and tradeable <br />pollution permits, development rights on private property that supports important <br />biological habitat can be disaggregated from the original land base and traded <br />freely on the open market. In this instance, owners of land providing habitat <br />would be allowed to trade or sell rights to development. Both development and <br />non-development interests would be eligible to buy these development rights. <br />To implement this type of system, the FWS would have to make the initial alloca- <br />tion of rights by determining how much of the particular habitats for candidate <br />species and other qualifying ecosystems would be eligible for development, and <br />then by distributing those rights among existing private land owners on a propor- <br />tional basis. For example, if the FWS determined that 15 percent of Habitat A <br />was eligible for development, each landowner of Habitat A would be authorized <br />to develop up to 15 percent of the land they own on Habitat A. The FWS deter- <br />minations on the amount of habitat eligible for development would be based on <br />sound biological and ecological data on the amount of habitat required to sustain <br />and maintain candidate species and overall biodiversity. <br />Stipulations: The initial FWS determination of how much of each habitat type <br />would be eligible for development would be firm, unless new habitat acreages <br />were created. Those parties seeking to develop more of their land than for which <br />they hold development rights would be obligated to obtain additional rights from <br />other parties. For example, if Developer A's property contains 40 acres of a <br />13 <br />