My WebLink
|
Help
|
About
|
Sign Out
Home
Browse
Search
9369 (2)
CWCB
>
UCREFRP
>
Public
>
9369 (2)
Metadata
Thumbnails
Annotations
Entry Properties
Last modified
7/14/2009 5:02:35 PM
Creation date
5/22/2009 5:42:54 PM
Metadata
Fields
Template:
UCREFRP
UCREFRP Catalog Number
9369
Author
Colorado Water Workshop.
Title
12th & 13th Annual Colorado Water Workshop.
USFW Year
1987.
USFW - Doc Type
Western State College of Colorado.
Copyright Material
NO
There are no annotations on this page.
Document management portal powered by Laserfiche WebLink 9 © 1998-2015
Laserfiche.
All rights reserved.
/
193
PDF
Print
Pages to print
Enter page numbers and/or page ranges separated by commas. For example, 1,3,5-12.
After downloading, print the document using a PDF reader (e.g. Adobe Reader).
Show annotations
View images
View plain text
<br />municipal uses have the secondary affect of eliminating or delaying new <br />diversions, instream values are not lost. <br /> <br />The conventional wisdom described above regarding the role of irrigation <br />in the West holds not only that water has been an important source of regional <br />growth, but that removing water from agriculture would have significant <br />negative economic effects. In fact, there is little evidence to support this <br />hypothesis. Direct economic impacts to the agricultural sector from loss of <br />irrigation water are measured by ,,~t economic value foregone and will be <br />registered on the products with the lowest value productivity. In the sectors <br />losing water (generally forage, and food and feed grain production), the net <br />economic value foregone for a 10 to 20 percent supply reduction will usually <br />fall in the range of $5-$30 per acre-foot. On the other hand, the gain in net <br />value of product or in a municipality's willingness to pay is likely to be at <br />least five to ten times as high. Indirect impacts, measured by income from <br />primary regional resources ("value added") and by employment per unit of water <br />(including multiplier effects), indicate that these secondary losses <br />associated with transferring water from agriculture, while not insignificant <br />in terms of either income flows or employment, are dwarfed by the gains in <br />nonagricultural sectors. In particular, the sectors most likely to be <br />affected (again, forage, and food and feed grains) yield relatively small <br />indirect employment and income effects when compared to those for emerging <br />urban sectors (Young, 1983). <br /> <br />The economic interests of farmers whose water is transferred to urban <br />uses are generally protected by existing state institutions, but transaction <br />costs may be high and decisions binary, i.e., water is sold or not sold. More <br />flexible and imaginative alternatives, including agricultural-municipal <br />drought insurance (an annual premium payment by cities to farmers for the <br />right to callout the irrigators in very dry years) or the movement of <br />conserved irrigation water to municipal uses. The state, through its <br />legislature and executive, could act to create the mechanisms that would make <br />it possible to include these options in the arena of agricultural-municipal <br />water bargaining. In addition, the State could anticipate how fast irrigation <br />water will be lost (this is likely to be slow--a few percent per year), so <br />that indirectly affected workers and businessmen are given time to adjust. <br /> <br />The second example--interstate water leasing--involves a grander scale. <br />The State might consider the establishment of conditions that would make it <br />possible to lease its as yet undeveloped Colorado River compact water to <br />others without requiring private water rights holders to establish a <br />beneficial use as a prerequisite to participate in lease arrangements. By <br />creating the kinds of conditions that would not require project construction <br />(the Bureau of Reclamation has all the storage necessary to effect any kind of <br />Upper Basin-Lower Basin transfer [Langbein, 1959]), the State of Colorado in <br />partnership with private water rights holders could realize some of the value <br />of its unused compact allocations. Moreover, by doing so it would be <br />establishing a clear ownership position by virtue of the lessee's <br />acknowledgement that, in order to use the water, it had to r'ent it from <br />Colorado. <br /> <br />A maturing water economy presents Colorado with a variety of opportunities. <br />In an environment where there is competition for money from every State agency, <br />every dollar must be spent wisely. Making it pasier for water users to take advan- <br />tage of interdependencies in water supply systems would stretch capital funds and <br />simultaneously improve system efficiency and protect instream flows. <br /> <br />-15- <br /> <br />*****Preliminary Version: Not for quotation or attribution without permission of <br />the authors.*** PRINTED WITHOUT BIBLIOGRAPHY, <br />
The URL can be used to link to this page
Your browser does not support the video tag.