My WebLink
|
Help
|
About
|
Sign Out
Home
Browse
Search
9369 (2)
CWCB
>
UCREFRP
>
Public
>
9369 (2)
Metadata
Thumbnails
Annotations
Entry Properties
Last modified
7/14/2009 5:02:35 PM
Creation date
5/22/2009 5:42:54 PM
Metadata
Fields
Template:
UCREFRP
UCREFRP Catalog Number
9369
Author
Colorado Water Workshop.
Title
12th & 13th Annual Colorado Water Workshop.
USFW Year
1987.
USFW - Doc Type
Western State College of Colorado.
Copyright Material
NO
There are no annotations on this page.
Document management portal powered by Laserfiche WebLink 9 © 1998-2015
Laserfiche.
All rights reserved.
/
193
PDF
Print
Pages to print
Enter page numbers and/or page ranges separated by commas. For example, 1,3,5-12.
After downloading, print the document using a PDF reader (e.g. Adobe Reader).
Show annotations
View images
View plain text
<br />The Paradox of Water--Its Value and Its Rhetoric. <br /> <br />A paradox arises in dealing with the value of water. The political and <br />media rhetoric asserts its enormous economic importance. This conventional <br />view, however, contrasts with the reality that the resource exhibits a <br />relatively low economic value at the margin. Conceptually correct empirical <br />estimates of the direct marginal value productivity of irrigation water <br />usually fall in the range of $25-75 per acre-foot (Young, 1984). For the <br />majority of crops the estimates are in the lower part of this range. Based on <br />the cost of supply, the value of water in the municipal sector is no more than <br />an order of magnitude greater. <br /> <br />In other words, resources devoted to water development, conservation or <br />management can justify a cost of only 1.5 to 3 cents per' ton for irrigation <br />and perhaps 30 cents per ton for household use. While a substantial total <br />economic value may still be implied for large water supply projects, the point <br />is. that the m~!:gi!l_~! value of irrigation water to the user is often <br />insufficient to justify major capital expenditures. (Compare, for example, <br />with other liquids important in modern economies. Gasoline retails in the <br />U.S. at about $330,000 per acre-foot, implying users are willing to pay 10,000 <br />to 20,000 times more per unit volume than they wi 11 for irrigation water). In <br />the municipal sector, although the value of water is greater, it seldom <br />compares with the rhetoric surrounding it. <br /> <br />Having looked at the value of water used in an application where it <br />usually has a market price, what can be said about the intrinsic value of the <br />natural system from which it is removed? Because aquatic <br />ecosystems---habitats, wetlands, and streams--are not traded in conventional <br />markets that reflect such values, other methods must be used. There are <br />direct methods, like contingent valuation (Le., asking individuals their <br />willingness to pay), and indirect methods that infer value from use. (For a <br />thorough review of both, see Stavins, 1984). In addition, there are other <br />survey methods that try to estimate "option values" and "existence values" <br />that are above and beyond what individuals would be willing to pay now for an <br />option to ensure accesS to, or existence of, an environmental resource in the <br />future. Another approach is to base the value of a natural system on the cost <br />of mitigating its loss, should it be destroyed. Appropriate application of <br />these methods can establish the value of natural systems and their associated <br />water resources. <br /> <br />The statement that aquatic ecosystems are not traded in the market is not <br />entirely true. There are states in which instream flow programs allow water <br />rights to be purchased for the protection of natural systems. Presumably, <br />rights are purchased at market rates and data on these purchases would provide <br />an indication of instream flow values. Moreover, ownership restrictions found <br />in some instream flow programs (e.g., Colorado's program prohibits private <br />ownership of instream rights) may reflect a concern that, were a market to <br />operate freely, instream flows values would set the price. (For example, <br />rafting companies might attempt to purchase the water rights necessary to <br />maintain minimum boating flows). Closing such interests out of the market <br />suggests there may be fear, in some quarters at least, that instream values <br />may exceed those of traditional "beneficial use" categories. <br /> <br />The point is, natural systems do have value, their value can be measured <br />(if only indirectly in certain cases), and, with regard to the economic <br /> <br />- 12 - <br />
The URL can be used to link to this page
Your browser does not support the video tag.