<br />framework describing the range of possible outcomes
<br />along with management actions that would be triggered
<br />by each outcome. Too frequently, this has proven difficult
<br />to accomplish for hatchery programs. Once begun, hatch-
<br />ery programs have considerable momentum and may be
<br />difficult to terminate or substantially change, even in the
<br />face of clear evidence that they are not accomplishing their
<br />goals. For example, Hilborn (1992) described a salmon
<br />hatchery in Oregon that, in spite of all attempts at remedi-
<br />al action, had been shown to be ineffective in producing
<br />adult fish. Nevertheless, it proved to be impossible to
<br />close the hatchery because of a fear that doing so would
<br />indicate a lack of commitment to the resource. As dis-
<br />cussed by Hilborn, this is an example of displacement of
<br />the original goal of producing fish to the goal of demon-
<br />strating an effort to produce fish.
<br />Third, fishery biologists often find themselves in a M&E
<br />catch-22 with respect to hatcheries: If they find no evidence
<br />of deleterious effects, it is difficult to argue for restrictive
<br />measures; if they do find harm, some will argue that restric-
<br />tive measures are unnecessary because there is no pure nat-
<br />ural population to worry about any more. A variation of this
<br />scenario is that by the time adverse effects become apparent,
<br />they (in combination with other factors) may have depressed
<br />the natural population to such an extent that aggressive
<br />supplementation is considered essential anyway.
<br />These factors by no means diminish the importance of
<br />M&E for hatchery programs. However, they demonstrate
<br />the folly of using M&E as an excuse for not rigorously
<br />addressing all risks up front and designing a program that
<br />is as risk-averse as possible from the outset.
<br />
<br />Where Do We Go from Here?
<br />
<br />A key step in resolving some of the controversies regard-
<br />ing fish hatcheries will be moving toward agreement on a
<br />common version (rather than two or more separate versions)
<br />of the realities about hatcheries. In my view, actions are need-
<br />ed in four major areas: identifying goals, conducting over-
<br />all costbenefit analyses to guide policy decisions, improv-
<br />ing the information base, and dealing with uncertainty.
<br />
<br />Goals
<br />
<br />To begin with, we must not only achieve greater clarity
<br />in articulating the goals of hatchery programs, but also en-
<br />sure the programs are developed to address fisheries man-
<br />agement needs. A given program may have a single major
<br />goal (e.g., to replace production lost through habitat block-
<br />age, to supplement an at-risk natural population), or it may
<br />have multiple goals (increase the abundance of naturally
<br />spawning fish while augmenting harvest opportunities).
<br />Second, it is important to determine whether the explic-
<br />it goals are inclusive enough. The following question should
<br />be asked: "Is pursuit of the major goal of the program like-
<br />ly to compromise the ability to achieve other fisheries man-
<br />agement or societal goals?" If so, then the goals of the pro-
<br />gram should be modified or expanded to reflect these other
<br />considerations. For example, the 1982 Fish and Wildlife
<br />Program developed by the Northwest Power Planning
<br />
<br />February 1999
<br />
<br />FISH CULTURE-PERSPECTIVE
<br />
<br />Council (NWPPC 1982) identified as its interim goal
<br />doubling the run size of salmon and steelhead in the Colum-
<br />bia River basin. As revised in 1994 (NWPPC 1994), the cur-
<br />rent goal is to double run size without loss of biological
<br />diversity. This revision of the goal statement reflects the belief
<br />that long-term sustainability of fisheries resources within
<br />the basin depends on conservation of natural populations.
<br />Third, fisheries managers, fish culturists, fishery biolo-
<br />gists, and conservation biologists should review the goals
<br />and, if possible, agree on general principles that will guide
<br />future management decisions. This will establish a solid
<br />basis for conducting the program under an adaptive manage-
<br />ment framework-if possible, using performance indicators
<br />to measure whether the program is adhering to the princi-
<br />ples and meeting the goals. Such a framework also should
<br />acknowledge that goals may change through time and pro-
<br />vide a mechanism for reevaluating the program if that occurs.
<br />
<br />Comprehensive Cost:benefit Analysis
<br />Once the fundamental goals of a hatchery program are
<br />agreed on, the next step is to identify its nature and scope.
<br />A wide variety of approaches is available, each of which
<br />may be appropriate under certain conditions. To deter-
<br />mine the most suitable type of program for a particular sit-
<br />uation, it is necessary to do a comprehensive cost:benefit
<br />analysis. This analysis takes the following basic form:
<br />
<br />Net benefit = [benefits to society + benefits to natural
<br />populations + benefits to ecosystems] - [costs to society
<br />+ costs to natural populations + costs to ecosystems]
<br />
<br />Conducting such an analysis is exceedingly challeng-
<br />ing. In the simplest scenario (use of artificial propagation
<br />to alleviate short-term extinction risk to natural popula-
<br />tions), the primary costs and benefits are in a common cur-
<br />rency, both being evaluated with respect to the natural pop-
<br />ulation. Even so, determining whether a particular program
<br />will have a net benefit to the natural population is far from
<br />easy. Furthermore, a comprehensive analysis of supplemen-
<br />tation also should include additional costs such as effects
<br />on other species or the environment, or fiscal expenditures
<br />that might otherwise be used for another purpose.
<br />The analysis becomes much more complex if the goals
<br />of the program include benefits to society as a whole
<br />rather than (or in addition to) benefits to natural popula-
<br />tions. Societal benefits might include those derived direct-
<br />ly from the hatchery program (more fish to harvest; more
<br />jobs for fishers, fish culturists, and fishery biologists; and
<br />meeting legal or tribal treaty obligations) as well as bene-
<br />fits that accrue indirectly from activities (hydropower, log-
<br />ging, agriculture) that are permitted because they are
<br />compensated for by the hatchery program. An analysis of
<br />this type requires comparing at least three types of curren-
<br />cies: fiscal expenditures to operate the program (measured
<br />in dollars), benefits to society (only some of which can eas-
<br />ily be measured in dollars), and costs and benefits to nat-
<br />ural populations and the environment. Placing an econom-
<br />ic value on living natural resources is a complex process,
<br />and literature on this topic is limited.
<br />
<br />Fisheries" 19
<br />
|