Laserfiche WebLink
<br />framework describing the range of possible outcomes <br />along with management actions that would be triggered <br />by each outcome. Too frequently, this has proven difficult <br />to accomplish for hatchery programs. Once begun, hatch- <br />ery programs have considerable momentum and may be <br />difficult to terminate or substantially change, even in the <br />face of clear evidence that they are not accomplishing their <br />goals. For example, Hilborn (1992) described a salmon <br />hatchery in Oregon that, in spite of all attempts at remedi- <br />al action, had been shown to be ineffective in producing <br />adult fish. Nevertheless, it proved to be impossible to <br />close the hatchery because of a fear that doing so would <br />indicate a lack of commitment to the resource. As dis- <br />cussed by Hilborn, this is an example of displacement of <br />the original goal of producing fish to the goal of demon- <br />strating an effort to produce fish. <br />Third, fishery biologists often find themselves in a M&E <br />catch-22 with respect to hatcheries: If they find no evidence <br />of deleterious effects, it is difficult to argue for restrictive <br />measures; if they do find harm, some will argue that restric- <br />tive measures are unnecessary because there is no pure nat- <br />ural population to worry about any more. A variation of this <br />scenario is that by the time adverse effects become apparent, <br />they (in combination with other factors) may have depressed <br />the natural population to such an extent that aggressive <br />supplementation is considered essential anyway. <br />These factors by no means diminish the importance of <br />M&E for hatchery programs. However, they demonstrate <br />the folly of using M&E as an excuse for not rigorously <br />addressing all risks up front and designing a program that <br />is as risk-averse as possible from the outset. <br /> <br />Where Do We Go from Here? <br /> <br />A key step in resolving some of the controversies regard- <br />ing fish hatcheries will be moving toward agreement on a <br />common version (rather than two or more separate versions) <br />of the realities about hatcheries. In my view, actions are need- <br />ed in four major areas: identifying goals, conducting over- <br />all costbenefit analyses to guide policy decisions, improv- <br />ing the information base, and dealing with uncertainty. <br /> <br />Goals <br /> <br />To begin with, we must not only achieve greater clarity <br />in articulating the goals of hatchery programs, but also en- <br />sure the programs are developed to address fisheries man- <br />agement needs. A given program may have a single major <br />goal (e.g., to replace production lost through habitat block- <br />age, to supplement an at-risk natural population), or it may <br />have multiple goals (increase the abundance of naturally <br />spawning fish while augmenting harvest opportunities). <br />Second, it is important to determine whether the explic- <br />it goals are inclusive enough. The following question should <br />be asked: "Is pursuit of the major goal of the program like- <br />ly to compromise the ability to achieve other fisheries man- <br />agement or societal goals?" If so, then the goals of the pro- <br />gram should be modified or expanded to reflect these other <br />considerations. For example, the 1982 Fish and Wildlife <br />Program developed by the Northwest Power Planning <br /> <br />February 1999 <br /> <br />FISH CULTURE-PERSPECTIVE <br /> <br />Council (NWPPC 1982) identified as its interim goal <br />doubling the run size of salmon and steelhead in the Colum- <br />bia River basin. As revised in 1994 (NWPPC 1994), the cur- <br />rent goal is to double run size without loss of biological <br />diversity. This revision of the goal statement reflects the belief <br />that long-term sustainability of fisheries resources within <br />the basin depends on conservation of natural populations. <br />Third, fisheries managers, fish culturists, fishery biolo- <br />gists, and conservation biologists should review the goals <br />and, if possible, agree on general principles that will guide <br />future management decisions. This will establish a solid <br />basis for conducting the program under an adaptive manage- <br />ment framework-if possible, using performance indicators <br />to measure whether the program is adhering to the princi- <br />ples and meeting the goals. Such a framework also should <br />acknowledge that goals may change through time and pro- <br />vide a mechanism for reevaluating the program if that occurs. <br /> <br />Comprehensive Cost:benefit Analysis <br />Once the fundamental goals of a hatchery program are <br />agreed on, the next step is to identify its nature and scope. <br />A wide variety of approaches is available, each of which <br />may be appropriate under certain conditions. To deter- <br />mine the most suitable type of program for a particular sit- <br />uation, it is necessary to do a comprehensive cost:benefit <br />analysis. This analysis takes the following basic form: <br /> <br />Net benefit = [benefits to society + benefits to natural <br />populations + benefits to ecosystems] - [costs to society <br />+ costs to natural populations + costs to ecosystems] <br /> <br />Conducting such an analysis is exceedingly challeng- <br />ing. In the simplest scenario (use of artificial propagation <br />to alleviate short-term extinction risk to natural popula- <br />tions), the primary costs and benefits are in a common cur- <br />rency, both being evaluated with respect to the natural pop- <br />ulation. Even so, determining whether a particular program <br />will have a net benefit to the natural population is far from <br />easy. Furthermore, a comprehensive analysis of supplemen- <br />tation also should include additional costs such as effects <br />on other species or the environment, or fiscal expenditures <br />that might otherwise be used for another purpose. <br />The analysis becomes much more complex if the goals <br />of the program include benefits to society as a whole <br />rather than (or in addition to) benefits to natural popula- <br />tions. Societal benefits might include those derived direct- <br />ly from the hatchery program (more fish to harvest; more <br />jobs for fishers, fish culturists, and fishery biologists; and <br />meeting legal or tribal treaty obligations) as well as bene- <br />fits that accrue indirectly from activities (hydropower, log- <br />ging, agriculture) that are permitted because they are <br />compensated for by the hatchery program. An analysis of <br />this type requires comparing at least three types of curren- <br />cies: fiscal expenditures to operate the program (measured <br />in dollars), benefits to society (only some of which can eas- <br />ily be measured in dollars), and costs and benefits to nat- <br />ural populations and the environment. Placing an econom- <br />ic value on living natural resources is a complex process, <br />and literature on this topic is limited. <br /> <br />Fisheries" 19 <br />