Laserfiche WebLink
<br />minnows outside the state for sale. In striking down the law, the Hughes Court ov rruled <br />Geer v. Connecticut, 161 U.S. 519 (1896), which had held that game birds, even when . <br />lawfully killed within the borders of Connecticut, could not be removed beyond those <br />borders. The Hughes Court noted that according to Geer, <br /> <br />the State had the power, as representative for its citizens, who "owned" in <br />common all wild animals within the State, to control not only the taking of <br />game but also the ownership of game that had been lawfully reduced to <br />possession. By virtue of this power, Connecticut could qualify the <br />ownership of wild game taken within the State by, for example, <br />prohibiting its removal from the State: "The common ownership imports <br />the right to keep the property, if the sovereign so chooses, always within <br />its jurisdiction for every purpose." <br /> <br />Hughes, 441 U.S. at 327 (quoting Geer v. Connecticut, 161 U.S. at 530). Prepa~ing to <br />overrule Geer, the Hughes Court observed that Geer's "erosion" had commenced a mere <br />fifteen years after it was decided. Hughes, 441 U.S. at 329. This erosion was be un by <br />West v. Kansas Natural Gas Co., 221 U.S. 229 (1911), which commented that i states <br />were allowed to engage in protectionist legislation, <br /> <br />embargo may be retaliated by embargo, and commerce will be halted at <br />state lines. And yet we have said that "in matters of foreign and interstate <br />commerce there are no state lines." In such commerce, instead of the <br />states, a new power appears and a new welfare, - a welfare which <br />transcends that of any state. But rather let us say it is constituted of the <br />welfare of all of the states, and that of each state is made the greater by a <br />division of its resources, natural and created, with every other state, and <br />those of every other state with it. This was the purpose, as it is the result, <br />of the interstate commerce clause of the Constitution of the United States. <br /> <br />. <br /> <br />ld. at 255 (inner quote not identified in original). See Commonwealth Edison <br />Montana, 453 U.S. 609, 618 (1981) ("The premise of our discrimination cases s that <br />'[t]he very purpose ofthe Commerce Clause was to create an area of free trade amo g the <br />several States.''') (quoting McLeod v. JE. Dilworth Co., 322 U.S. 327, 330 ( 944)) <br />(citing Hunt v. Washington Apple Advertising Comm 'n, 432 U.S. 333, 350 (1977); oston <br />Stock Exchange v. State Tax Comm 'n, 429 U.S. 318, 328 (1977)). <br /> <br /> <br /> <br />Proceeding to the issue at hand, Hughes noted Toomer v. Witsell, 334 U. . 385 <br />(1948). Toomer dealt with statutes by which South Carolina was attempting to pro ect its <br />off-shore shrimp stocks. As Connecticut had claimed ownership of game birds, so South <br />Carolina claimed ownership ofthese shrimp. However, the Toomer Court opined t at <br /> <br />[t]he whole ownership theory. . . is now generally regarded as but a <br />fiction expressive in legal shorthand of the importance to its people that a <br />State have power to preserve and regulate the exploitation of an important <br />resource. And there is no necessary conflict between that vital policy <br /> <br />. <br /> <br />6 <br />