My WebLink
|
Help
|
About
|
Sign Out
Home
Browse
Search
WSP09067
CWCB
>
Water Supply Protection
>
Backfile
>
9001-10000
>
WSP09067
Metadata
Thumbnails
Annotations
Entry Properties
Last modified
1/26/2010 2:50:57 PM
Creation date
10/12/2006 3:26:32 AM
Metadata
Fields
Template:
Water Supply Protection
File Number
8030
Description
Section D General Correspondence-Other Organizations
State
CO
Basin
Statewide
Date
7/1/1972
Author
USWRC
Title
US Water Resources Council - Proposed Principles and Standards - Summary Analysis
Water Supply Pro - Doc Type
Report/Study
There are no annotations on this page.
Document management portal powered by Laserfiche WebLink 9 © 1998-2015
Laserfiche.
All rights reserved.
/
195
PDF
Print
Pages to print
Enter page numbers and/or page ranges separated by commas. For example, 1,3,5-12.
After downloading, print the document using a PDF reader (e.g. Adobe Reader).
Show annotations
View images
View plain text
<br />OOG33E <br /> <br />24 <br /> <br />"If one does not accept revealed market valuations of <br />resource services--mutually. determined as they are by technical <br />transformation conditions and money demands--as the appropriate <br />measure of cost, then one must employ some other measure of cost <br />for any or even all resource inputs, if one is obligated to under- <br />take a cost-benefit calculus. The 'some other measure' must <br />necessarily be the result of a valuation process. The results of <br />such valuation process have also corne to be termed 'shadow <br />pricing', but it is a valuation process nevertheless. At this <br />point, the question of 'whose' shadow price and what are the <br />principles by which it is set arise. <br /> <br />"There is nothing inherently wrong with developing shadow <br />prices (indeed, my method of calculating the private opportunity <br />return implicitly employs such a technique to take account of the <br />'tax wedge I upon the yields from private investment). However, <br />use of a shadow pricing approach, unless one is careful, is <br />susceptible to obfuscating the distinction between cost and demand, <br />or more precisely in the context of cost-benefit analysis, between <br />cost and benefits. . . ." <br /> <br />* * * * * <br /> <br />"But, overall, I find the social discount rate concept a <br />rather disingenuous way of addressing the subject of evaluating <br />government programs. It is a way of providing a cost rationale <br />for something when the issue should be explicitly hammered out in <br />terms of demands, or preferences. If the same approach is <br />applied to other inputs. . . it makes a shambles of any attempt to <br />conduct cost-benefit or cost-effectiveness analysis of government <br />programs. The real operational content of all this, it seems to <br />me, amounts to the assertion that political decisiorunakers, when <br />employing the coercive power of the state, can override any set of <br />preferences that its citizens would otherwise register in the <br />market place. But this has always been true. However, I see no <br />reason to confuse the concepts of cost and benefits (which are <br />admittedly fragile) in the process. It would be better, it would <br />seem, to dispense with cost-benefit endeavor entirely. <br /> <br />i. <br /> <br />"Thus far I have only discussed the 'principle' pertaining to <br />costing capital inputs employed for goverrunent resource-using <br />activities. The problem of determining empirically the 'opportu_ <br />nity cost of capital,' is a separate issue, and entails some com- <br />plexities which I have addressed elsewhere. I estimate that rate, <br />before taxes, to be around ten percent, after an allowance for <br />inflation. . . ." <br />
The URL can be used to link to this page
Your browser does not support the video tag.