My WebLink
|
Help
|
About
|
Sign Out
Home
Browse
Search
WSP01328
CWCB
>
Water Supply Protection
>
Backfile
>
1001-2000
>
WSP01328
Metadata
Thumbnails
Annotations
Entry Properties
Last modified
7/28/2009 11:21:01 PM
Creation date
10/11/2006 10:20:07 PM
Metadata
Fields
Template:
Water Supply Protection
File Number
8030
Description
Section "D" General Correspondence - Other Organizations/Agencies (Alpha, not Basin Related)
Date
12/21/1971
Author
WRC
Title
Proposed Principles and Standards for Planning Water and Related Land Resources-Notice of Public Hearing, Water Resources Council
Water Supply Pro - Doc Type
Publication
There are no annotations on this page.
Document management portal powered by Laserfiche WebLink 9 © 1998-2015
Laserfiche.
All rights reserved.
/
55
PDF
Print
Pages to print
Enter page numbers and/or page ranges separated by commas. For example, 1,3,5-12.
After downloading, print the document using a PDF reader (e.g. Adobe Reader).
Show annotations
View images
View plain text
<br />to the Viet Nam war. He then weights <br />these average rates by the proportion of <br />investment in the diff'erent parts of the <br />priva.te sector during the .later part; of <br />this period. Finally, he reduces this ag- <br />gregate average rate by the avemge rate <br />of inflation In the longer period. The <br />resulting estimate of the real average <br />rate of return in the private sector is 10.4 <br />percent: for this concept, this ~timation <br />procedure is probably accurate within a. <br />:tl percent range. Recognizing the two <br />conceptual problems discussed above, in- <br />clusion of the rate of return on State <br />and local government investments would <br />somewhat lower this. rate and a reduc- <br />tion in non-Federal investment dis- <br />placed by additional Federal investment <br />would lead to a marginal rate somewhat <br />above the average. On net. it appears <br />that the average of the marginal returns <br />on physical investment in the non- <br />FederaLsector is around 10 percent. and <br />additional evidence also suggests that <br />the marginal retwn on investment in <br />educatton is approximately equal to the <br />rate of return on physi.cal investment. <br />Moreover, there is strong reason to be- <br />l1eve that the real rate of return in the <br />non-Federal sector has been roughly <br />constant over the entire period since the <br />Korean war. The structural cond1tions <br />that determine this rate are the long- <br />. run investment prospects in the U.S. <br />economy and the levels -ef taxes on cap- . <br />ital or the earnings on capitaL The long- <br />run investment prospects appear to be <br />roughly constant. Although the corpo- <br />rate income tax has been reduced <br />slightly since the Korean war, property <br />taxes have been increased by a roughly <br />equal magnitude. A sign1:ficant redis- <br />tribution of investment activities within <br />the non-Federal sector would also <br />change the average of the rates of re- <br />tum, but this has not. been observed. <br />This suggests that a frequent recalcula- <br />tion of the Stockflsch estimate need not <br />be made unless there is evidence of a <br />significant change in these structural <br />conditions. <br />It Is Important. to recognlze that the <br />stabtlity of the real rate ot return in the <br />non-Federal sector is not inconsistent <br />with the observed var1ance of the rates <br />on marketed debt I.nBtruments. Changes <br />"':'1n the yields on Government bonds and <br />other debt Instruments primarlly reflect <br />conditions--such as changes in ilie an- <br />ticipated inflation, monetary policy. and <br />the distribution between equity and debt <br />financing-that are unrelated to the real <br />rate of return on investment. <br />In summary, ilie conceptual and em- <br />piricalissues are not fully resolved. The <br />above discussion, however, suggests that <br />the appropriate rate for evaluating Gov- <br />ernment investment decisions is approx- <br />imatelY 10 percent and is SUbstantially <br />invariant to short-term changes in <br />economic and money market conditiollB. <br />3. Selection of a speci/lc rate for water <br />resource projects. The revealed prefer- <br />ences of the Federal politica.l process <br />clearly indicate a desire.to transfer in- <br />come to the people in specific regions by <br />subsidizing water resource projects. In <br /> <br />NOTICES <br /> <br />the past; these subsidies have been im- <br />plemented in several ways but most lm- <br />pol'tantly by the \IBe of o.n Interest rate <br />to evalus.te these projects that Is lawer <br />than that for alternative Federal and <br />non-Federal investments. Accepting the <br />legitimacy of the political process in <br />determining income transfers and sub- <br />sidies. the use of. a low interest rate, un- <br />fortrmately,1s often an ineM.cient instru- <br />ment for these purposes because it also <br />biases the design of these projects to- <br />ward those with higher near-term costs <br />and lower near-term benefits. <br />ReCOgnizing both the objectives of <br />subsidizing water resource projects and <br />the objective of an efficient combina.tion <br />among and between Federal and non- <br />Federal investment activittes, a 7-per- <br />cent rate will be used. for evaluating <br />water resource projects durtng the nex.t <br />5 years. Use of a 7-percent rate will fa- <br />cilitate Implementation of one of the <br />basic purpose of multiple objectives <br />planning by allowing more comparable <br />consideration of environmental qUe.lity <br />objectives. Less capitalinteD.5ive projects, <br />scaled mainly to meet near-term needs, <br />will'result in relativelY more efficient use <br />of Federal e.nd non-FederaJ Investment <br />toward meeting increasing critical water <br />needs. given current budgeta.ry con- <br />stmlnts, <br />It 18 sometimes argued that the dJs- <br />count rate 00 be used in evaluating Fed- <br />eral investment opportunJ.ties should be <br />based on the cost of Federal borrowing <br />(the cost of money to the Treasury). It <br />should be noted that. properly calculated. <br />the cost of Federal borrowing tricludes <br />not only the yield rate on Treasury obl1- <br />gatJons but also tax revenuea foregone <br />on returns to private borrowing displaced <br />by Federal borrowing, comm:iss1oI18 paid <br />on sales of bonds. and' administrative <br />costs of borrowing. After the yield rate. <br />the most significant of these is foregone <br />tax revenues. <br />The fulll cost of Federal long-term bor- <br />rowing, .for generally preva1!ing economic <br />,collBideratlollB. is at least 7 percent and <br />can be as high as 10 percent. The exact <br />figure depends on how much tax revenue <br />is foregone. This, in turn. depends on the <br />distribution of income from foregone in- <br />vestment among corporations. tncUvid- <br />uals, and State/local governments. <br />Thus. the 7-percent rate established <br />above, approaches both the opportun.1ty <br />cost o.nd the tola.! cost of Federa.! <br />borrowing. <br /> <br />E. CONSIDERATION AND COMPARISON OF <br />ALTERNATIVES <br /> <br />A range of JX)SBible alternatives to meet <br />needs o.nd problems. including types of <br />measures and alternatives CBipable of ap- <br />plication by various levels of govern- <br />ment and by nongovernmental inter- <br />....., should be studied, These alterna- <br />tives should be evaluated or judged 6S to <br />their ooutrtbutlon to the multiobjectlves. <br />Plans, or increments thereto, wUl not <br />be recommended. tor Federal develop- <br />ment th&t. although they have positive <br />oontrlbutions to the multlobJect.ives, <br /> <br />24167 <br /> <br />would physically or economically pre- <br />clude alternative non-Federal plans <br />which would Ilkel.Y be undertaken In the <br />absence of the Federal plan and which <br />would more effectively contribute to the <br />multiobjectives when comparably evalu- <br />ated according to the principles. <br />The alternative non-Federal plan that <br />would likely he physically displaced or <br />lCOOIlomicallY "prec.luded with develOp- <br />ment of the Federal plan, or increments <br />thereto, will be evalua.ted for purposes of <br />this determinatton on a oomparable <br />ba.sls with the proposed Federal plan <br />with respect to their beneficial and ad- <br />verse effects on the multiobjectives, in- <br />cluding the 'treatment of national eco- <br />nomic development effects and the dis- <br />conn.t rate used in the evaluation. Taxes <br />foregone on the proposed F'edereJ. plan <br />and taxes paid on the non-Federal al- <br />ternative. will be excluded in such com- <br />parisons for the evaluation of the na- <br />tional econo~c development objective. <br /> <br />1'. PERIOD OF ANALYSIS <br /> <br />The period of analys1s will be the lesser <br />of: (1) The period of time over which <br />the plan.w1l1 serve a useful P\.1I1X>5C con- <br />B1dering prdbBble technological trends <br />affecting various alternatives: or (2) the <br />period of time when turther "dIscounting <br />of beneficial and adverse effects will have <br />no appreciable result on design. Where <br />pertinent, however, appropriate consid- <br />eratton will be given to long-term en- <br />vironmental factors which may extend <br />beyond periods Blgni1lco.nt for analysis of <br />effect6 for national or regional economic <br />development. <br />SaJ.vage value remaining a.t the end at <br />the period of ansJys\s should be taken ' <br />into account for Income-producing fea- <br />tures of the plan. <br />For the environmental objectives, the <br />goal may be to achieve a level of env1ron- <br />menta.! quaJlty during or at the end of <br />the period of anaJysls o.nd to maIntain <br />this level Into the Indellnlte future, <br />One hundred years will nornmll.Y be <br />considered the upper limit of the period <br />of analysis, o.nd shorter periods will be <br />used whenever appropriate for any of <br />the constde:ra.tions described above. <br /> <br />G. SCHEDULING <br />Plo.ns shoul1:l be scheduled for imple- <br />mentation in relation to needs so toot <br />desired multl:Objective beneficial effects <br />are achieved effectively. Beneficial and <br />ad.verse e1fects occurring according to <br />d1:IIerent patterns in time are affected <br />differently by the discount' process when <br />plans are scheduled for implementation <br />at alternative future tlmes~ Therefore, <br />plan fonnulation,should analyze the al- <br />ternative schedules of implementation to <br />identify the schedule that would result <br />in the most' desirable mix of contribu- <br />tions to the multiobjectives when the <br />beneficial and adverse effects of a plan <br />are appropriately disCOWlted. <br />While beneficial and adverse effects <br />to\V'8.rd the multiobjectives will accrue <br />over different time frames for the alter- <br />native implementation scheduloo the <br />discontinued equlvalent of such bene- <br />ficial and adverse effects to be considered <br /> <br />No. 246--Pt. D--4 <br /> <br />FEDERAL REGISTER, YOLo 36, NO. 245-TUESDAY, DECEMBER 21, 1971 <br />
The URL can be used to link to this page
Your browser does not support the video tag.