Laserfiche WebLink
<br />I <br />I <br />I <br />'1 <br />t <br />I <br />I <br />I <br />I <br />I <br />I <br />I <br />I <br />I <br />I <br />I <br />I <br />I <br />I <br /> <br />ever existed outside of folklore and dictum) is rapidly falling out of favor across the West. <br />The great majority .of western states have come to recognize-to a limited extent-the role <br />of instream uses within the prior appropriation system. <br /> <br />Barriers still stand, however, to the full integration of instream uses into state <br />water allocation systems. Barriers (such as the "second class" treatment of instream flows <br />discussed above) are not due to any natural incompatibility between instream rights and <br />the prior appropriation doctrine. Far from it; the doctrine is fully up to the task of <br />accommodating modern needs. All that remains is to eliminate those legislative <br />restrictions which are essentially alien to the doctrine's nature. <br /> <br />The most pervasive and frustrating limitation on instream rights in most western <br />states is the prohibition against ownership of instream rights by persons other than a <br />designated state entity. This prohibition is a curious twist on the prior appropriation <br />doctrine. It reflects a basic discomfort with the concept of instream rights and an <br />underlying distrust of those entities which may seek to acquire them, particularly <br />environmental groups and the federal government. Many states, it seems, have struck a <br />compromise in which instream values are recognized as legitimate, but the people acting <br />through the prior appropriation doctrine are not trusted to fairly allocate those rights. <br /> <br />Ironically, then, the drafters of such programs have turned away from the market- <br />based principles which underlie the prior appropriation system, and have embraced <br />principles of command-and-control resource allocation-socialism, if you will-with respect <br />to instream rights.47 In short, western states for over a century have entrusted farmers, <br />municipalities, and hydroelectric companies with making fundamental decisions about <br />where water will flow. Yet these same states suddenly lose confidence in the prior <br />appropriation system when it comes time to allocate resources between consumptive <br />users and those whose interests are benefitted by leaving water in rivers. <br /> <br />Much of the hostility to instream flow programs, it seems, is based on <br />misapprehension of their function. Properly administered, instream uses pose no threat <br />to the valuable property rights of existing users. While they may "tie up" a stream and <br />complicate efforts of new users to develop sources of supply, so do all water rights. That <br />is the nature of property rights generally. In the long run, the people are better served <br />by the state facilitating negotiation and market transactions than they are served by <br />government control of instream flows by fiat. <br /> <br />Indeed, an effective instream flow program is the West's best defense against <br />threats to the integrity of state control posed by the federal government, over-zealous <br />environmentallitigators, and out-of-state users. Farmers, cities, developers, and <br />industries-as well as recreational users-each may benefit from a viable free market in <br />instream flows. Such a market, free of unnecessary government interference, is what the <br />prior appropriation doctrine was meant to provide. <br /> <br />2-13 <br />