My WebLink
|
Help
|
About
|
Sign Out
Home
Browse
Search
7793
CWCB
>
UCREFRP
>
Copyright
>
7793
Metadata
Thumbnails
Annotations
Entry Properties
Last modified
7/14/2009 5:01:46 PM
Creation date
5/22/2009 12:33:25 PM
Metadata
Fields
Template:
UCREFRP
UCREFRP Catalog Number
7793
Author
Douglas, A. J. and R. L. Johnson
Title
Instream Flow Assessment and Economic Valuation
USFW Year
1993
USFW - Doc Type
A Survey of Nonmarket Benefits Research
Copyright Material
YES
There are no annotations on this page.
Document management portal powered by Laserfiche WebLink 9 © 1998-2015
Laserfiche.
All rights reserved.
/
16
PDF
Print
Pages to print
Enter page numbers and/or page ranges separated by commas. For example, 1,3,5-12.
After downloading, print the document using a PDF reader (e.g. Adobe Reader).
Show annotations
View images
View plain text
<br />INSTREAM FLOW <br /> <br />99 <br /> <br />iD the 1940's on four of the five streams that feed the lake, water levels at Mono Lake <br />dropped sharply. Avian habitat provided by the marshes and islets of the lake <br />diminished sharply. Shoreline recreational opportunities were adversely affected <br />by diminished lake water levels. Off-site benefits of restoring surface water levels <br />at Mono Lake per California household were $42 per annum, and represented 90% <br />of the total aggregate value. The social opportunity cost of maintaining higher <br />Mono Lake water levels was estimated to be $2.64 per California household <br />per annum. <br />Loomis et al.7 19900 estimated the benefits of reallocating San Joaquin River <br />waters to maintain positive instream flows for this California river. The social costs <br />of rewatering the streamreach in order to partially restore the San Joaquin River fall <br />chinook salmon run include foregone agricultural output and hydropower. Loomis <br />et al.3o show that the estimated nonmarket benefits of more than $2 billion per <br />annum for restoring the San Joaquin River salmon run are significantly greater than <br />the social costs. . <br />Walsh et al.22 estimated the benefits and costs of having various Colorado rivers be <br />officially designated by Congress as Wild and Scenic Rivers. The Colorado rivers in <br />question would then become protected from development pressures by the Federal <br />Wild and Scenic Rivers Act of 1968. They present important data on per capita <br />benefits and costs for protecting these rivers; they estimate and use a miles-of- <br />stream-reach-protected versus net-marginal-benefits-of-protection relation to calcu- <br />late the optimal level of protection. The costs of protecting the river stem from <br />foregone grazing, mining, and timber harvesting activities. In addition, two sizeable <br />planned water development projects would be permanently forestalled. Irrigation <br />water from planned impoundments is mentioned explicitly by Walsh et al.22 as one <br />of the outputs of hypothetical development projects. They estimate that the marginal <br />social benefits conferred exceed the marginal social costs of protection from <br />further development for 13 Colorado rivers. The present value in 1983 of the net <br />off-site benefits from protecting the three most valuable rivers including the <br />Cache la Poudre, Colorado, and Elk Rivers for 50 years were $485 million at a <br />discount rate of 7.875%. The present value for the net user benefits for the three <br />rivers was $113 million.22 <br />The large off-site nonmarket benefits estimated by Loomis et al.,7 Walsh et al.,22 <br />and Loomis23 have sharper policy implications than earlier contingent value method <br />on-site benefits studies. Note that the survey instruments of these three existence <br />benefits studies clearly delineate a baseline reference condition. For example, the <br />non market amenity in Walsh et al.22 is protecting miles of streamreach for certain <br />carefully designated streamreaches from further construction of dams, reservoirs, <br />and other water diversions or development that alters their free-flowing condition. <br />The baseline condition is, therefore, the pre-1983 state of the rivers.22 The baseline <br />condition in Loomis et al. 7 is a completely extinct salmon run. The salient issue is one <br />of defining the amenity in relatively simple terms that facilitate the definition of the <br />baseline condition. Kahneman and Koetsch,27 for example, estimate benefits for a <br />broad environmental amenity that is so complex and multi-faceted that it is difficult <br />to quantify amenity improvements, and therefore difficult to define the baseline. <br /> <br />OFF-SITE BENEFITS AND HYDROPOWER <br /> <br />The policy implications of recent studies employing state-of-the art techniques, large <br />data bases, and carefully designed survey instruments to estimate similar instream <br />
The URL can be used to link to this page
Your browser does not support the video tag.