My WebLink
|
Help
|
About
|
Sign Out
Home
Browse
Search
7393
CWCB
>
UCREFRP
>
Public
>
7393
Metadata
Thumbnails
Annotations
Entry Properties
Last modified
7/14/2009 5:02:30 PM
Creation date
5/20/2009 5:14:13 PM
Metadata
Fields
Template:
UCREFRP
UCREFRP Catalog Number
7393
Author
Harrington, W.
Title
Endangered Species Protection and Water Resource Development.
USFW Year
1980.
USFW - Doc Type
LA-8278-MS,
Copyright Material
NO
There are no annotations on this page.
Document management portal powered by Laserfiche WebLink 9 © 1998-2015
Laserfiche.
All rights reserved.
/
65
PDF
Print
Pages to print
Enter page numbers and/or page ranges separated by commas. For example, 1,3,5-12.
After downloading, print the document using a PDF reader (e.g. Adobe Reader).
Show annotations
View images
View plain text
<br />knowledge about the behavior and habitat requirements of the species to be <br />protec ted. For abundant species, the needed information is either known or <br />can be co llec ted through experiments with management techniques. Often, how- <br />ever, very little is known about the habits of endangered or rare species, and <br />predicting the response of such species to management techniques is very prob- <br />lematical. That is, wildlife management may be more appropriate as a supple- <br />ment to control of development than as a replacement for it. A third reason <br />has to do with the incentives facing an agency with the responsibility of <br />protecting endangered species. The costs of wildlife management come out of <br />the agency's budget, whereas the costs of regulation are paid by the regulatee. <br />With many species to protect and limited resources to do so, an agency has an <br />incentive to export the costs when possible. Therefore, even if substitution <br />of wildlife management is otherwise attractive, it could be thwarted by insti- <br />tutional barriers. <br />3. Distributional Consequences. Protection of endangered species pro- <br />vides benefits to society, but it also imposes costs in opportunities foregone. <br />How are these costs to be distributed? More specifically, given an economic <br />development that must be circumscribed or canceled to avoid impacts on endan- <br />gered species or critical habitat, should the costs of doing so be borne by <br />the developer? <br />From the standpoint of fairness, this is not an altogether easy question <br />to answer. Ownership of land or other resources confers rights which, while <br />not abso lute, are none the less substantial. According to the Constitution, if <br />the government is to prevent those rights from being exercised, the owner must <br />be compensated. In the context of endangered spec ies protec tion, what sorts <br />of landowner activities may be regulated, and what sorts require compensation? <br />Most people would agree, for example, that the killing of endangered species <br />on private land could be regulated without unduly diminishing the value of the <br />property right. But what of "reasonable" use of land, ordinary economic acti- <br />vities that inadvertently affect the habitat of endangered species? Regulation <br />of this sort of activity would, moreover, seem to violate at least one of the <br />canons of equity used in public finance: willingness~to-pay. Application of <br />the willingness-to-pay concept would suggest that the cost of endangered spe- <br />cies protec tion should be borne by the public at large or perhaps by preser- <br />vationists with an especially strong interest in endangered species protection. <br /> <br />8 <br />
The URL can be used to link to this page
Your browser does not support the video tag.