Laserfiche WebLink
<br />below the full cost of production and distribution. Therefore, <br />local benefits can be greater than national benefits because of <br />this subsidy. <br />Before the water can be used, it must be taken out of the <br />river. In arid climates, water must be stored in reservoirs if a <br />year-round supply is to be available. The amount of water that <br />can be stored and distributed with existing dams and aqueducts <br />is limited. If demand for water exceeds the capacity of the <br />storage and distribution system, additional facilities will be <br />required. WOSA water benefits will have one value if only the <br />currently built water resource projects on the river will be used <br />in conjunction with WOSA. The value will be quite different if <br />those projects that have been authorized by the Colorado River <br />Basin Project Act (P.L. 90-537) are built, so that more water <br />can be distributed and used. <br />At present, not all the water that flows down the River is <br />used. If WOSA is undertaken on a large scale, the added water <br />will flow down the River w'ithout being dra\vn out in either the <br />Upper or Lower Basins. The added water will have three <br />possible benefits: a slight improvement in water quality, an <br />improvement in the reliability of river flow, and increased <br />hydropower generation. The Mexican Treaty obligation will go <br />on being met with leftover water, for which there is no com- <br />petitive use. The improvement in water quality would allow a <br />yearly saving of $2.5 million in water quality management pro- <br />grams that have been proposed. The hydropower generated by <br />the WOSA water in the generating stations on the river would <br />save a yearly $5.3 million in fuel that would otherwise be <br />burned in older, less efficient steam electric stations. We have <br />not been able to put a value on the improved river flow relia- <br />bility, but it would probably be small. <br />The Colorado River Basin Project Act of 1968 (P.L. <br />90-537) declared the Mexican Treaty to be a national obliga- <br />tion that shall be met by any water augmentation project <br />planned under the Act and authorized by Congress. In addi- <br />tion, the Act authorized the Central Arizona Project and five <br /> <br />ECONOMIC EFFECTS <br /> <br />53 <br /> <br />SNOWPACK, CLOUD-SEEDING, AND THE COLORADO RIVER <br /> <br />anteeing a minimum allocation to California. Shortages in the <br />water allocation were to be borne first by the Central Arizona <br />Project. Congress also declared in the legislation that it recog- <br />nized a future need to augment the water supply of the river. It <br />stated that when the river is augmented, the obligation of a <br />treaty to supply Colorado River water to Mexico that was <br />agreed upon in 1944 would take the first priority. It also stated <br />that the costs of satisfying the Mexican obligation would be <br />borne by the federal government. <br />There is reason to believe that an operational WOSA pro- <br />gram in the Upper Colorado River Basin would not satisfy the <br />conditions that Congress may have had in mind when it estab- <br />lished this augmentation policy for the river. Some sort of spe- <br />cific Congressional action, or legal litigation, would be re- <br />quired to allocate WOSA water to the Mexican Treaty. If the <br />water should be allocated to Mexico, it would foreclose any <br />opportunity for forming an innovative public policy to deal with <br />the problems created by a WOSA program. <br /> <br /> <br />Water Benefits <br /> <br />The benefit of water is simply its value to a user. To a man dying <br />of thirst, a gallon of water may be priceless, but a million gallons <br />would not be a million times more valuable. A mati who uses <br />water to grow crops is not going to buy that water at a price so <br />high he loses money on his product. <br />In the arid west, so much water is used in irrigated agri- <br />culture that all other water uses could easily be met by transfers <br />from agriculture. Theoretically, if water could be freely ex- <br />changed, the farmer would be willing to sell his as soon as he <br />could make more money selling his water than he could by <br />farming. This means that the benefit to the nation cannot be <br />greater than the price the farmer would be willing to pay for <br />water. However, in much of the west, water supplies are not <br />rationed by the price of water in a free market, but by adminis- <br />trative means. Water is made available to irrigators at prices <br /> <br />52 <br /> <br />'. <br /> <br />1\..'... <br /> <br />'i <br /> <br />Jl, <br /> <br />~ <br />'. <br />